I recently read a blog
post about the coming catastrophic collapse of the U.S. economy and the
destruction of all our wealth. This genre of writing is familiar, but it
author’s errors are nonetheless instructive. While the author may be what
Keynes called a “monetary crank,” his errors highlight some of challenges we
face in understanding what money actually is. In this post I hypothesize that a folk psychology underlies our theory of money; a psychology based on anxieties about
our interdependence, and the conditions of contingency that shape our
experience.
The post’s author
writes, “You
see that 300 percent increase in the money supply we've experienced . . Much
of it is sitting in excess reserves at the Fed and with the big banks. These
funds haven't made it into the markets and the economy yet. But it's a
mathematical certainty that once this dam breaks, and this money passes through
the reserves and hits the markets, inflation will surge.”
(http://www.moneynews.com/MKTNews/billionaires-dump-economist-stock/2012/08/29/id/450265?PROMO_CODE=110D8-1)
The metaphor of the dam breaking suggests that money is a physical
force, not unlike a raging river, which operates under its own mathematical
laws, much as a gravitational field exerts an inexorable pull
on objects in its field. But nothing could be farther from the truth. It is useful to ask if
this misconception is simply a question of ignorance, or is it motivated? Does
it serve any purpose?
It is useful to look at the numbers behind the metaphor. Banks are
required to hold a minimum amount of reserves in their own checking deposits
with the Federal Reserve Bank (“the Fed”). The following chart traces the amount
of excess reserves that banks held in
these checking deposits with the Fed since 2009. It has grown by the astounding
amount of $1.8 trillion.
As the post we quoted suggests, the bank system has been flooded with
money. But how did the money get there and what does it consist of? The Fed buys treasury bonds, bills and
mortgage-backed securities from mutual, hedge and pension funds and deposits
the money in sellers’ bank accounts. This means that this money is now
available to a seller’s bank as the basis for lending to borrowers, and thus
counts as its reserves. (Recall that banks can lend out far more than their
reserves because it is unlikely that all the depositors will demand their money
at the same time. When this happens, we say that there is a “run on the bank.”)
But where did this money and the subsequent reserves come from? The answer
is from nowhere. The Fed created it
with keystrokes. Reserves are like points in a football game. The Fed bought
the bills and bonds and credited the seller by adding points to both the seller’s
account and to the bank’s “score,” or the amount of its recorded reserves. When
game officials add points on the scoreboard in a baseball stadium, we never
wonder where the points came from. We should not in this case either. Moreover,
in the first instance this does not change the money available to the public. Bonds
and Treasury bills are ways in which institutions, non-profits, households and mutual
funds can earn interest on the money they own, much as individuals do with a
savings account. When a pension fund sells bonds to the Fed for money, it is in
effect moving its money from a savings account to a checking account. The
amount of an individual and institution’s financial assets, at least initially,
remains unchanged.
There is a common misconception, held even by some economists, that
banks are intermediaries, linking people with money to lend, to people needing
money to borrow. This is called the “loanable funds doctrine.” This is not
right. Instead, banks create money whenever they make a loan. This is why the
process is called credit creation. In
this of way of thinking, as modern monetary theory emphasizes, loans create
deposits, deposits don’t create loans. (See Modern
Money Theory, by Randall Wray, Palgrave, 2012). If a bank gives me a loan
it does not give me a barrel full of cash. It simply creates an account on its
spreadsheet and marks down the requisite “points” in dollars. Keystrokes again.
This also means that when the Fed increases a member bank’s score – the measure
of its reserves—the banks do not automatically give out more loans. The money
is not sitting there creating pressure. It is denominated in keystrokes.
Instead, banks lend only when they can identify credit worthy borrowers. One
reason that banks had so much excess reserves in the years after the Great
Recession is that they were wary of extending credit. This is also why the
Fed’s program of “quantitative easing’ – buying bonds and bills and crediting
member banks with reserves, has not caused inflation.
The seeming mystery of how money can come from nothing is resolved by
recognizing that economic life is lived forwardly.
Businesses have to spend money, before they earn it, and credit, or what is
sometimes called “working capital,” makes this possible. This is why sometimes
a fast growing company goes out of business. It cannot get enough credit to
finance its growing expenses in advance
of its hoped for revenues. Credit in this sense is a measure of a bank’s and business
owner’s shared conception of the future, which by definition does not yet
exist. It is a signal from the future, as the bank and borrowers imagine it together.
Money instantiates this signal.
.
In this sense credit represents a victory of abstraction. Human
culture has found a way of representing numerically something that does not
exist materially. It is not unlike, the way in which Newton’s theory of gravity
accounted for the observed motion of objects, by abstracting from its physical
manifestations and positing a force that could only be described
mathematically. We can’t “touch” gravity. Instead, it is instantiated only in
the numerical relationship between objects.
So one question is why do people persist in thinking about money as a
“thing,” as a force that can break through a dam, or as an object that is
passed like a tennis ball from a lender to a borrower. I can think of two
hypotheses that draw on psychoanalytic thinking. Both presume that human
culture creates “social defenses” against anxiety, which if experienced
directly would be distressing and discomfiting.
Consider the extreme case of “gold bugs.” These are people who believe
that the only basis for a national currency is gold, and that the Central Banks
of all countries should promise to redeem their national currency into gold
upon demand. This was in fact the basis for the historic but now defunct international
gold standard. The conviction underlying this idea is that states and their
representatives cannot be trusted, that left to their own devices they will
“print money” in order to confiscate our real resources; our houses, cars,
televisions, coal and gas. If political and economic elites are foresworn to redeem paper into gold they
will be constrained by the amount of extant gold and the amount that can be
mined. Never mind that the amount of gold available as backing is in some
degree arbitrary. Never mind as well that if there is insufficient gold,
countries will experience deflation because there is too little paper currency
to support the desired volume of exchange. Gold bugs discount the salience of
these likely problems partly because their larger vision is tinged with
paranoia. They worry that a cabal of unseen forces, call them Jewish bankers or
Freemasons, controls us, and that only gold will free us.
I suggest that we can generalize from this extreme case. The gold bug has a fantasy of a social relationship, albeit a paranoiac one. Once we
understand that money is nothing but the expression of our relatedness, we must
recognize the ways in which we are interdependent in world wide circuit of exchange. So one
hypothesis is that we want to see money as thing, as a defense against the
anxiety we feel when we see how interdependent we really are. Karl Marx’s conception of “commodity
fetishism” is helpful here. He argued that we tend to see an economic exchange
as the relationship between money and goods, rather than what it ultimately is,
a relationship between people. We treat money as magical, as if it can conjure
up objects without considering the underlying social organization that money
sets into motion. Thus for example, we buy cheap clothing from Bangladesh imagining
that we are exchanging money for clothing. But in fact we are setting in motion
a social process through which poor people work under unsafe and sometime life
threatening conditions. It could very well be anxiety provoking to acknowledge
our personal connection to this social fact. That is why of course activists
insist that trade be fair as well as free.
Marx’s use of the term, “fetishism” is also suggestive to the
psychoanalytic listener, and may provide some additional insight. For example,
many men are comfortable in a sexual situation, at least initially, only if
they can focus on a body part, for example, a woman’s breast, leg, buttocks or
foot. This is very common, as is evident in most commercial pornography. In the
extreme, a male fetishist may need a prop, for example a shoe, in order to
become sexually excited. He endows the fetish or shoe with magical
properties. One hypothesis is that the this focus on a part, rather than the
whole, and on a material object, rather than on the relationship with the woman, enables the
man to exercise control over the conditions that excite him. Absent the fetish
his excitement would turn into anxiety. The conception that money is a physical object,
that is separate from the complicated relationships it sets into motion, and
from the relationships it exposes, shares some of these features. (Note to my skeptical reader. Invoking sexuality does not mean that people's relationship to money is sexualized Rather, by drawing on sexual experience in its vividness and specificity we gain insight into motivation and its constituents more generally. This is one way to interpret psychoanalysis' privileging of sex as a key to motivation.)
The term “magical” points to another and perhaps more speculative
hypothesis. I came across the following video, which gives a coherent presentation
of credit creation, emphasizing for example the creation of credit out of
nothing and the system of account settlement and clearing. (http://www.youtube.com/watch?v=KyDU4X8GSmE)
Yet the tone and import of the video suggests conspiracy. It is introduced with
dark sounding music, and images of a grim reaper type of figure chained to a rock
of “debt” and swinging a mallet to break the chain. The video scrolls through a
quote by Woodrow Wilson, the 28th president of the United States, “Some
of the biggest men in the United States, in the field of commerce and
manufacture, are afraid of somebody. They know that there is a power somewhere
so organized, so subtle, so watchful, so interlocked, so complete, so pervasive
that they had better not speak above their breath when they speak in
condemnation of it.” The video’s central message is that there is something
nefarious about the fact that credit is created “ex-nihilo,” or to translate
the Latin, “out of nothing.”
The phrase “ex-nihilo” is in fact linked to the idea of credit
creation (http://en.wikipedia.org/wiki/Ex_nihilo),
but was originally a theological
description of God’s powers. In Judeo-Christian
theology only God can create ex-nihilo. This is why the Old Testament counsels
the Israelites to avoid magic and magicians, “No witch shall you let live,” (Exodus,
22: 17). Moreover, the economist Fredrick Hayek argues that in the early stages of capitalism, “Activities that
appear to add to available wealth ‘out of nothing,’ without physical re-creation
and by merely rearranging what already exists, stink of sorcery.” As David Hawkes notes this was one basis for the
revulsion against usury in Renaissance England; not that it was simply unjust
but that it was supernatural. Money “procreated” so to speak, in the form of
interest payments added to capital. Yet it was lifeless. As he writes, “Usury
was magic perfected by other means.” (The
Culture of Usury in Renaissance England, Palgrave, 2010)
Today most of us do not
believe in magic. Instead we enjoy magic shows in which stage magicians makes
objects appear out of nothing -- ex-nihilo -- but only in fun, though we are often astonished. I want to suggest
nonetheless that there is an experiential basis for our anxieties about "ex-nihilo,"
particularly in a secular age. If we think seriously about our own existence,
it must seem that we came into the world, ex-nihilo. Of course we understand
how babies are born, but our own existence is so arbitrary. After all, none of
us have existed since the beginning of the universe and yet here we are now,
suddenly! How can that be?
The arbitrary can be
frightening. It is a portal to chaos. But we should also remember that the
other side of arbitrary is “contingency.” Our world is not determined, and this
becomes the basis for creative work of all kinds. That is why credit creation
can support entrepreneurship, which is, after all, the creative arrangement of
resources in new ways.
One speculative hypothesis is
that that we project these existential anxieties onto a “folk-theory” about
money. At the extreme, some people develop a theory of money in which “hidden
forces,” who create credit out of nothing, use this power to enslave us, in
other words to eliminate contingency and the capacity for creative work. This fantasy
paradoxically provides relief because it suggests that someone, some shadowy
network, is actually in control. All is not chaos, and if we are smart enough,
we can control the controllers. A larger number of people, less likely to be
drawn to conspiratorial thinking, persists in thinking of money as a physical
object that operates mechanically, as a way of avoiding the uncomfortable idea
that the course of our lives, like our birth, is entirely contingent and
unpredictable. The laws of money like the laws of physics provide scaffolding,
an “invisible hand.” This may be one reason why economists did not anticipate
the financial crisis that led to the Great Recession. This sense of contingency is also the basis for the criticism that George Soros, the famous investor, has of modern economic theory. His name for it is "reflexivity." The challenge then, is to
accept the arbitrary, and then see the creative opportunities in contingency,
both in our individual lives and in the social world we create together. We can use credit and money creatively.